Review of Joseph K. Angell, A Treatise on the Common Law in Relation to
Water Courses, 2 Am. Jurist 25, 30-34 (1829).
Art. II.--THE LAW OF WATER PRIVILEGES.
A Treatise on the Common Law in relation to Water Courses, intended more
particularly as an Illustration of the Rights and Duties of the Owners and Occupants of
Water Privileges. To which is added an Appendix, containing the principal Adjudged Cases.
By Joseph K. Angell, Counsellor at Law. Boston. Wells & Lilly. 1824.
The profession are indebted to Mr. Angell for the great labor he has bestowed upon
several branches of the law. The work, whose title is prefixed to this article, has been
before the public for a considerable time; and the approbation with which it has been
received by our learned jurists, while it is the evidence of its merit, renders it
unnecessary for us to enlarge upon its object, or its excellencies and defects.
The law in relation to Water Courses is every day becoming more important, as
our mills and manufactories multiply, and the improvements in the science of agriculture
lead to a more general application of water to the purposes of husbandry.
It is not our purpose, however, to discuss so broad a subject as the law in relation to
the various rights and interests which make up the property in water courses; but we shall
confine these remarks to the respective rights of parties interested in those streams of
water which are suitable for mill privileges. The law upon this subject, aside from our
peculiar statute regulations, may be considered as well settled, and to a good degree
accurately defined; and yet, in the application of these well-defined rules, difficulties
often arise, and resort is often had to courts of justice to remove doubts which cannot
otherwise be settled. A stranger may not, for instance, divert nor essentially diminish
the water of a stream which has been appropriated to the working of an ancient mill. But
whether the water of such stream has been actually so appropriated, whether the mill is an
ancient one, or whether by disuse of a portion of the stream the right to enjoy it has not
been surrendered, may often be questions difficult of solution.
If difficulties may arise under the well-established principles of the common law, how
much wider is the door for embarrassments to counsel and courts in Massachusetts, Maine,
Rhode Island, Virginia, and Kentucky, where a series of laws singular and extraordinary in
their provisions, have been enacted, which, though at variance with the common law, have
not substituted any system which obviates the necessity of resorting to the principles of
the common law to determine the questions which are from time to time arising under their
operation.
Few, comparatively, of these questions have been the subjects of judicial cognizance,
partly because they have been unimportant in themselves, and partly because parties have
been unwilling to incur the risk and expense of settling questions in courts of justice so
doubtful in their nature that no counsel, however learned in the law, could confidently
give advice concerning them. If these statutes are constitutionally binding upon the
citizen, and courts, and are hereafter to be made the subjects of adjudication by our
judiciary, many new principles; and much judicial legislation, must, we conceive, be
resorted to in order to determine the respective rights of the litigant parties.
* * *
Although the common law is thus entitled to our confidence and veneration as a system,
it must obviously be necessary, at times, to modify or annul certain parts of it, in order
to adapt it to the changes in the wants and condition of society. Such was the origin of
those statutes which were early passed for the support and regulation of
mills, which authorized their owners to raise and keep up a head of water upon
neighboring lands not their own. The first of these was passed in Massachusetts in 1713,
during the reign of Queen Anne. The preamble of the statute recites, that whereas it
hath been found by experience that when some persons in this province have been at great
cost and expenses for building of mills, serviceable for the public good, and benefit
of the town or considerable neighborhood in or near to which they have been erected,
that in raising a suitable head of water for that service it hath sometimes so happened
that some small quantity of lands or meadows have been thereby flowed and
damnified, not belonging to the owner or owners of such mill or mills, whereby several
controversies and lawsuits have arisen; for the prevention whereof for the future
the provisions of the statue which then follow were made. Here, then, we have a history of
the origin of this statute, which authorized the occupant of a mill to keep up the pond
flowed for the use of it, subject to pay such annual sum in damages to the land owner as
should be assessed by a jury drawn for that purpose. This statute took away the right
which till then the land owner possessed, of removing from his land a nuisance by which he
suffered, nor did it provide him an adequate remedy or recompense for such injury.
But the circumstances under which the people of the colonies were placed at and
anterior to that time, serve to explain the reason of its enactment and of the public
acquiescence for so long a time in its provisions. The country had been in a state of slow
progress from a wilderness to cultivation. Lands were of comparatively little value, while
the support of corn and saw mills for the grinding of their bread stuffs and the erection
of their houses, was a measure of vital necessity to the scattered population of the
state, and consequently encouraged in every possible manner. Mill sites were in some
instances appropriated from common lands by the votes of their proprietors, and mills were
often exempted from taxation by the corporations within which they were established. In
many instances they were erected in parts of the country still covered by the primitive
forest, and where the extent of the flowing and even the owners of the lands were unknown.
Mills therefore, thus established, might with propriety be considered public
easements, and as of public convenience and necessity, and the property of
private individuals might, with great propriety, be appropriated for their support under
suitable restrictions. So where lands were flowed which had never been appropriated to
private owners, or where lands of little or no value were greatly enhanced by the
establishment of what was so necessary to their enjoyment, it was certainly a measure of
expediency, if not of justice, that such mill owners should be permitted to continue the
enjoyment of what they had thus appropriated.
The laws of Maine on this subject are similar to those of Massachusetts, being a part
of the code common to the two states. The laws of the other states, as far as we have had
an opportunity to examine them, excepting those of Rhode Island, differ materially from
those of Massachusetts and Maine. The statutes of Connecticut only confirm the doctrine of
the common law, by providing that if any person dam any stream, or turn it out of
its course, to the prejudice of any town, proprietors, or any particular person, the same
shall be deemed a common nuisance, and be removed as such.
By the laws of Rhode Island, as they stood formerly, if a person intending to erect a
water-grist-mill proposed to rest a part of his dam upon the land of another,
or to flow any lands belonging to others, he must previously apply to the court for
a jury to view the premises, report whether the proposed dam would flow so as to encroach
upon the buildings, yards, &c. of another, and estimate the damage. In the revised
laws of 1798 of that state, the party erecting a mill has a right, as in Massachusetts and
Maine, to flow the lands first, being subject to pay the damage subsequently assessed by
the viewing jury.
The laws of Virginia and Kentucky are very similar to those of Rhode Island before the
alteration of these latter in 1798. According to the Virginia code, a person owning land
on one side of a stream who proposes to erect a water-grist-mill, or other machine
or engine useful to the public, may make application to the court, through which, by
appraisement by a jury, he obtains the title to the opposite bank, and the right to flow
the land of other proprietors, provided the flowing does not extend to a house, yard,
&c.
Whatever reasons might have led to the original enactment of the statutes we have
alluded to, they have ceased to exist with the disappearance of the forests from our
valleys, the increase of our population, the introduction of the arts of husbandry, and
the multiplication of mills and manufactories, which supply the public convenience, and
reward those who have thus invested capital. It could not, therefore, we are persuaded,
have been upon the ground of public necessity that in 1796 the provisions of the
provincial act of Massachusetts were substantially re-enacted; and we cannot, in the
language of Chief Justice Parker, (in Stowell v. Flagg) help thinking that
this statute was incautiously copied from the ancient colonial, and provincial acts which
were passed when the use of mills, from the scarcity of them, bore a much greater value,
compared to the land used for the purposes of agriculture, than at present. And we
may add, that this remark becomes more forcible in proportion as the lands in the
Commonwealth become more and more valuable.
Since the re-enactment of this law in 1796, the subject has been one of frequent
examination by courts of that state, and five several additional acts in regard to the
support and regulation of mills, have been passed by the legislature. In all
these acts the same principle as to the occupation of anothers lands, and the
payment of annual damages only, has been retained; and a recent attempt so to modify the
principle as to secure to the land owner, at his option, the actual value of the land so
taken from him, and thereby the means of purchasing other lands, has been defeated. If
such property must be taken in any manner from one citizen for the benefit and profit of
another, it would be more analogous to the provisions of the statutes which authorize the
appropriation of private lands for public uses, as in the cases of roads, canals, &c.,
that the damages done by the mill owner to the former should be paid in gross, and at
once, than the present mode of doling it out in annual pittances.
Under the present system of the laws of Massachusetts on this subject, the yeomanry of
that state, especially the small farmers, often feel that they are oppressed, and the
question is often asked, whether the exercise of such a power by one citizen over another can
be constitutional? It is certainly a very unusual and extraordinary provision of the
law. I may not seize my neighbors goods, except by process of law, against his
consent, even though I may offer him their full value in return. I may not plough my
neighbors land, even though the thorn and the thistle alone flourish there under the
sluggish husbandry of its owner. I may not obscure the light from the ancient cottage
window, though poverty and weakness alone may have enjoyed its cheerful influence; nor may
I poison the water or air that has, for years, given health and comfort to my neighbor,
though the trade I may follow would enrich my coffers, and accommodate the neighborhood.
But the ordinary rules of right and wrong, as to the enjoyment of private property, seem
not to apply to estates which border upon any of the beautiful and healthy streams which
enliven our scenery. They may be sacrificed to the speculating spirit of the manufacturer.
No matter with what labor acquired, no matter with what fond associations connected, the
farmer may be obliged to yield his acres to anothers enjoyment; and the soil which
his fathers may have tilled, the tree which sheltered him in his childhood, the scenes of
his early sports, and the very graves of his kindred, may fade beneath the hand of the
manufacturer, and the slimy pool which drives his spindles may send forth its miasmata
where the green meadow or the waving harvest once greeted the eye. And for this, the
recompense to be sought is an annuity to be estimated by strangers.
It is nothing against the argument to be drawn from facts like these, that much of the
land flowed by dams across our mill streams is of comparatively little value. If a state
of things in any measure like that we have here supposed has, in fact, existed,--and that
it has, we could prove by cases which have been notorious,--it is a question of not a
little moment, whether a law which authorizes such injuries can be consistent with those
fundamental political principles incorporated into most of our constitutions of
government. The rights which are guarantied to the citizen in these, are in accordance
with the principles of natural justice, and among them is that of acquiring,
possessing, and protecting property, and that no part of the property of an
individual can with justice be taken from him or applied to public uses without his
own consent, or that of the representative body of the people. But we no where find
the right to apply the property of any one against his consent to private uses,
and, on the contrary, it is provided in the constitution of the United States, that no
person shall be deprived of his property without due process of law.
We would, in this connexion, quote the language of Chancellor Kent, (2 Com. 276) as
expressing what we have endeavored to give more in detail. It must undoubtedly rest
in the wisdom of the legislature to determine when public uses require the assumption of
private property, and if they should take it for a purpose not of a public nature, as if
the legislature should take the property of A and give it to B, the law would be
unconstitutional and void. And we do not see how a legislature can delegate a
greater power than it possesses itself, or wherein consists the distinction between the
taking of property itself, and the taking of the enjoyment of that property and whatever
makes it worth possessing.
We are not aware that the constitutionality of this law has ever been discussed at all
at large before our courts, although in the case of Stowell v. Flagg (11 Mass. R.
364) it seems to have been settled that the legislature of Massachusetts have a right to
substitute the statute process by jury for the recovery of damages occasioned by flowing
instead of the common law remedy by action. But we would venture the remark, that this
dictum is very far from deciding that a legislature may, by a prospective act,
authorize the commission of such an injury, or empower individuals to continue to enjoy an
easement thus obtained. If the statute referred only to the recovery of damages for past
injuries, the reasoning of the court might well apply. It is said that the legislature
may declare that for an assault and battery an action of the case shall be brought
instead of an action of trespass; but we conceive that no legislature could
authorize, beforehand, A B to committ an assault and battery upon C D, although it might
see fit to change the form of the remedy. In regard to the statute relating to mills, the
mill owner is not merely made liable in a particular manner for the injury he does, but he
is also authorized to continue the injury--to continue the occupation and enjoyment
of anothers estate forever; which, we apprehend, is altogether unlike any
other assumption of private property usually contemplated by our constitutions, and as
being within the principle of the case of Bowman v. Middleton, (1 Bays Rep.
252) which settles, if any case were necessary, that a legislature has no right to
transfer to one man the freehold of another against his consent.
These may be called the popular objections to the laws under review, and yet there are
other considerations connected with them which should not be overlooked. These laws have
been fruitful sources of litigation, and although many of the questions which first arose
under their operation have been settled, we apprehend that the most important and
difficult ones yet remain to be determined. As the property in mill privileges becomes
more and more valuable with the increase of manufacturing in the state, many new and nice
questions must arise, which, under the fostering care of self-willed litigants, promise to
furnish a rich harvest for the now somewhat barren fields of litigation. What lawyer can,
for instance, instruct his client as to what precisely shall constitute an occupancy of a
mill site? whether this must be by a mill and dam, or a dam alone? Or how can he define to
him the extent to which he may retain the water of a stream by means of reservoirs for the
contingent uses of his mill?--a right which a mill owner has been held entitled to by the
case of Wolcott M. Co. v. Upham (5 Pick. 292). Or how can he point out to the owner
of lands which have been rendered worthless by flowing, the mode of obtaining adequate
damages for his injuries, if the mill owner should cease to flow the land? These are
questions which, we presume, are often asked a country practitioner; and some of them, we
apprehend, cannot be settled satisfactorily, till some hardy sufferer under the law shall
appeal to the courts to fix the limits of his rights by judicial legislation.
That we may not be misunderstood, let us suppose a common and simple case. A and B own
lands adjoining each other, and near the boundary line of their lands there is a
waterfall, sufficient for carrying one mill only. By the common law the owner of the upper
lands could alone occupy it, because, in the case we suppose, the owner of the lower lands
must flow back the water upon his neighbors land in order to obtain his power. But
by these statutes the site is open for the occupation of either. If both undertake to
occupy it, what shall either do to secure it to himself? Suppose they begin
simultaneously, is the occupation to be the erection of a mill? If so, the least important
establishment shall exclude the other; and a turning lathe or a saw-mill might render
worthless an extensive manufactory, because of the time taken in completing it. Then,
again, what shall constitute a mill: the building alone without its water wheels and
gearings? or must it all be completed for operation? If a mill is not necessary to the
occupation of a privilege, but it may be made by the erection of a dam, when shall such an
occupation be considered as made? with the first stone or timber laid, or only by
completing the dam? and if with the first operations of constructing it, shall it be by
the first stone or timber placed in the stream, or by the first furrow ploughed upon the
bank? And if, according as the rule shall be settled, the occupancy of the contending
parties shall be held to be simultaneous, which of the parties shall prevail; the one
above, who has the common law right, or the one below, who has the physical power of
rendering the others works worthless and inoperative?
These are questions, we apprehend, not easily settled in the present state of the laws.
And even if we suppose the question of precedency established, the difficulties in the
case may not be entirely removed. A reservoir may be needed to supply the mill thus
erected. How far above the site of his mill may the owner erect his reservoir? If at the
distance at which the one referred to in the Wolcott Company and Upham was erected, why
not at the distance of twenty or fifty miles, if the course of the stream permitted? and
if he has erected his reservoir, what shall be the rights of those who shall subsequently
erect mills between the reservoir and his mill? Must they be controlled, as to the
quantity of water flowing along the stream, by the whim or necessity of one far below
them, to be flooded one day by the excess, and kept idle the next day from a want of the
natural flow of the current?
But we are not disposed to pursue these inquiries, which we apprehend may one day be
subjects of litigation, if the laws shall remain as they now are. There are other
objections to these laws which we an only allude to, from the length to which this article
has been unexpectedly extended. Estates are often valuable only from the water privileges
upon them, which may be destroyed by the erection of dams below them, whereby powers of
little value may be created, and such estates may be in the hands of minors who cannot
sell, or poor tenants who cannot occupy them in time to prevent such a destruction to
their property. Estates too, which from their situation might be increasing in value or by
improvements which every farmer has it in his power to make upon them, would repay the
labor so bestowed upon them many fold, are, under this law, rendered incapable of
improvement, and the damages to the owner are too often estimated rather by what the
estate is at the time of its occupation, than what it might become by any increasing value
from its relative situation, or other circumstances.
It is true that the legislature of Massachusetts have, of late, relaxed a little from
the severity of the operations of this law, by providing a more adequate recompense to the
land owner than a mere estimation of the damages actually done to the land flowed. But
even the statute of 1824, c. 153, which authorizes a jury in such cases to estimate other
than the mere damages to the land, may be and often is, an altogether inadequate remedy.
It may perhaps be asked what remedy can be proposed which shall do justice to the
manufacturer and the farmer, and secure to each their respective rights, and protect the
interests of the public?
We would not, by any means, do aught to injure the manufacturing interests of our
country. To the eastern and middle states, manufactures are as essential to the prosperity
of the citizens, as the overflowing of the Nile is to the fertility of Egypt, and the
sustenance of its inhabitants. We would not, therefore, do anything which can destroy the
privileges already occupied. But we see not why these statutes which have been under
consideration, should not be repealed so far as future occupations of mill sites are
concerned. Restore the citizen to his common law rights; compel the capitalist, who may
hereafter wish to invest his money in manufacturing, to resort to the same means to
acquire the real estate that he would occupy, which a farmer or mechanic are compelled to
adopt,--to purchase it of the owner; make the rights of our citizens, in regard to their
property, as equal as the original constitution intended they should be, and we are not
apprehensive that manufacturing would flourish any the less. If it would, we say, let its
progress be checked. If it cannot be supported without this burden on the landholder, it
ought not to be supported by violent and forcible proceedings. It does not require such a
law in England, nor in many of our states where manufacturing is flourishing, nor do we
believe it needs it here. But if the measure we recommend should be thought too strong, we
suggest whether it is not the best policy of the manufacturer, as well as the landholder,
so to modify the present law that the actual value of the lands flowed should be estimated
by the
jury, to whom the subject is referred, and that the manufacturer should be compelled to
purchase it at such price, if the land owner prefers to sell the fee of the estate to
receiving an annuity out of it. This rule is already adopted in the Virginia and Kentucky
laws. A proposition like this has once or more been before our legislature of
Massachusetts, and rejected by that body. But we are confident that such a modification of
the law would be favorable to the manufacturer, since the interest of the sum he might be
obliged to pay for the land flowed by him, would often be less than the annual damages
which would be assessed in favor of the farmer. And the farmer could better afford to take
up with that sum in gross, than to receive his annual damages, because he is deprived of
the means of converting his labor into money on his land, or of increasing its value by
art and industry the moment it is drowned by the manufacturer. We have, therefore, been
surprised that a modification of the statutes so equitable and favorable to the parties
concerned, should have been lost in the legislature.
Although this amendment would not restore the common law to the citizen, it would
obviate many difficulties. But it would still leave the field of litigation open, and we
should have to wait for a long series of judicial decisions before the law upon the
subject would become settled.
The remarks which we have made will apply, in a great degree, to other states the laws
of which authorize the taking away or flowing of land without the consent of the owner.
EOD |